The Diff

This is an audio version of the free newsletter. Read the newsletter at thediff.co, and subscribe for an additional 3 posts (and podcasts!) per week.
  • (00:00) - The Quality Factor
  • (05:21) - Predictions
  • (07:03) - The 4Chan of Crypto
  • (07:54) - Adverse Selection
  • (08:57) - AI and Ads
  • (09:59) - Algorithmic Collusion

What is The Diff?

The Diff is a newsletter exploring the technologies, companies, and trends that are making the future high-variance. Posts range from in-depth company profiles, applied financial theory, strategy breakdowns and macroeconomics.

## The Quality Factor

A surprising stylized fact about markets is that, in general, it pays to own stocks that have high margins, stable earnings, and low leverage. You can hardly finish saying the intuitive explanation—that these are better businesses that will profitably grow in size over time—without interrupting yourself to ask why that wouldn't be instantly reflected in their valuations. The claim behind the quality factor is not just that these companies will do well, but that they'll continue to do better than investors expect.

It should be hard for this to persist, and there three ways to frame the explanation for why:

1. The most boring explanation is that investors have artificially limited leverage. Most of them think of the money they're managing in terms of assets under management, not daily P&L fluctuation, but in the latter model, a $10 million position in a mature consumer staples company is much bigger than a $4 million position in a crypto-miner-pivoting-to-high-performance-computing company. Some investors have a mandate that requires them to use low leverage, but also to be fully-invested, so if they want to maximize returns they need to shun quality companies and pick through the garbage instead.
2. A related explanation, which overlaps with this, is the lottery-ticket phenomenon: take any asset class, stratify it by risk, and you'll generally find that the highest-risk bucket has the worst risk-adjusted returns—tiny stocks go to zero, low-margin companies go bust, low-rated bonds default, etc., and the successes don't offset this. It's part of the same phenomenon, but perhaps more about behavioral biases than institutional constraints: people anchor to assessments of once-great companies and imagine that they'll mean revert, or fail to distinguish between 10%, 1%, and 0.1% odds of some positive catalyst.
3. It's also possible, and quite likely, that quality stocks were underpriced in the past, and that part of their outperformance is the one-time gain from the market recognizing this. A century-old company that never loses money just doesn't need to pay investors as much to hold it as a newer and less secure company does. Many of these businesses traded at market multiples in the 80s, a slight premium in the 90s, and a larger one since. (Though the roster of safe businesses has changed—in the 90s, pharma companies were the classic quality safe-haven category, but mostly traded below their late-2000 highs until the early 2010s.)

There's also a meta argument running through all of this: it makes sense for these stocks to outperform over time if investing is a form of entertainment, or a kind of gambling with some element of skill. But it makes sense for them to underperform if investing is a passive way to save—it's hard to be more passive than believing that people will keep on buying Clorox bleach, Hershey's kisses, and Diet Coke at roughly the same pace they already do, while commodity producers, growth stocks, financial services businesses, etc. are all prone to unpleasant surprises.

They're also easier to think about: it's just very straightforward to project continued growth for these businesses—easy to see how Google will add incremental ad units and keep capturing more search volume; or how Microsoft will find more products to sell to its corporate customers, who are themselves consistently adding headcount; or how Meta will, whatever the cost, shove its way into the lead in any new form of online social interaction. These companies are, in general, very good places to work, so there's the added perk for investors—when they think about how their money's being made, it's a pleasant thought.

Investing in low-quality companies is not so pleasant. The mood swings for a quality/growth investor revolve around whether a company is exceptional or merely pretty great, but if you're backing a steel mill, a mismanaged local bank, a software company that went ex-growth before it went free cash flow positive, etc., you can expect a litany of annoyances.

And yet, over the careers of basically every investor today, the price of avoiding all of that brain damage is negative. Smaller stocks and junkier companies are a good proving ground, but there's ample evidence that the best investors slowly shift towards quality companies—Buffett is the obvious example, but the crop of value-turned-growth fund managers of the 2000s and 2010s also exemplifies this. Sometimes there's a lower return on investment from digging up the best obscure turnaround story than there is in finding a good reason to hold Netflix for one quarter longer.

It's hard for this to persist forever, and high-quality companies with low growth trade at multiples similar to where they traded when rates were effectively zero. So the quality factor might be a case of investors making a discovery one stock at a time—realizing that small, cheap stocks were hard to scale but that larger, quality companies could compound indefinitely—and then converted that into a systematic strategy. But unlike approaches that directly reference valuation (e.g. the value factor) or that try to take advantage of imperfectly rational investor behavior (momentum), the quality factor alone doesn't make any reference to valuation: if every company with steady growth and stable margins double in price tomorrow, they'd all still show up as quality stocks on the same screen, and a passive investor using that factor would continue to own them. An insidious feature of systematic investing is that the backtest looks best when the strategy is crowded.

----

Disclosure: Long MSFT, META.

## Elsewhere

### Predictions

Coming into this year, my prediction, which I made publicly numerous times, was that since Biden and Trump have been public figures for my entire lifetime, and are currently two of the most famous people in human history, there was no point in paying attention to the campaign until maybe late October. This take aged badly.

The very high-level way I think about predictions is that you're trying to isolate a small number of variables that really matter, and pay close attention to those variables. There's a streetlight effect at work, where the features you want to predict are the ones where you can plausibly have an edge. Political discourse has a tendency to wildly over-extrapolate—in a first-past-the-post system, each party is going to nominate someone who has a reasonable shot at winning, and the person in the lead is going to flip from time to time. So another thing you can think about with predictions is choosing a different moment of the distribution: if the mean outcome is a toss-up, there can be alpha in saying that the variance will be overestimated and that you should bet against anything other than a 50/50 outcome. (And it is, incidentally, a pretty reasonable baseline assumption that whatever polling numbers come out this week, in the wake of an assassination attempt and a convention, will mean-revert a bit thereafter.)

But sometimes there's a new factor that just wasn't in the model. This is one good reason to be very cautious about selling volatility, even if it statistically works most of the time. The reason it works is that the equilibrium price for options bakes in some rough estimate, on the part of options sellers, about the probability of extreme events that aren't in the model at all. They spend all day thinking about known unknowns and weird contingencies, and even then need to bake in some margin of error for the unknown-unknowns, too.

### The 4Chan of Crypto

Subcultures sometimes go through a sort of stigma parallax, where a negative term that's applied to them often enough loses its sting and becomes a way for members to signal loyalty instead. So it's not surprising that one of the important players in the current memecoin trend calls itself pump.fun and and borrows some of its design elements from 4chan. They're deliberately spinning it as a fun game rather than as some kind of serious financial enterprise (though the SEC does not have a great sense of humor about this kind of thing). But it's also revealing about what altcoins are, currently, for: they are a kind of low-stakes recreation, with some tiny chance of outsized profits that isn't tied to anything that can be analyzed in the real world. If the first wave of memecoins was a cynical attempt to ride the hype, this generation is explicitly targeting people who are in on the joke.

### Adverse Selection

In other gambling-related news: sports betting services are capping bet sizes for their most successful users. A fun equilibrium in finance is that any time there is some group that puts immense resources into finding the right bets to make, their counterparties will invest roughly similar resources in not trading with them. In equities, payment for order flow is one way to achieve this—in the latter case, there's an explicit attempt to value trading against retail investors instead of institutions. Online gambling venues combine the functions of exchanges, clearinghouses, and market-makers, and of course their profits come from the typical biases gamblers have—betting on long shots, backing the home team, overestimating the persistence of winning streaks, etc. What's interesting is that they're still letting players gamble when they have an edge. If someone controls the full stack, and can identify smarter players, the optimal strategy is not to refuse to deal with them. Instead, it's to give them just enough bet size to make their bets worthwhile, and then to adjust pricing for everyone else accordingly.

### AI and Ads

The Diff has been arguing for a while that ads are the natural way to monetize generative AI, both because LLMs are an extension of search and because they can be tweaked to deliver a more commercial message. Google is inching in this direction by moving some ad placements closer to their generative search results.

What this also highlights is another reason ad-driven companies like generative AI: it makes the process of running a given ad even more opaque. Whatever tradeoff Google is accepting between user satisfaction and revenue per search is visible to Google but invisible to the advertiser, so if a given price/performance ratio is satisfactory, the value of any improvement in that tradeoff accrues directly to Google rather than to the advertiser. The best companies are always optimizing for future growth rate over current revenue, so for many product decisions they make today, the right question to ask is: does this set them up for higher growth in 2025?

### Algorithmic Collusion

The DOJ is planning to sue RealPage for enabling algorithmic collusion. This is a topic we've covered before in The Diff ($): demonstrating it requires a deep understanding of industry economics, and requires disentangling cause and effect in a case where they're fundamentally hard to analyze. Rents have risen, in part because of limits on supply; better pricing software on its own makes landlords better at capturing those gains, and if the software encourages them to collude, then there's an even bigger gain. Normally, what kills off price-fixing is some combination of regulation and defection, but if there isn't an easy way to defect—i.e. occupancy is already high and landlords have trouble building new properties—then regulation ends up being the only option. The earlier Diff piece was somewhat skeptical about algorithmic collusion, because the market in question was hotel casinos, and room rates are just one part of the bundle that they're selling. But when the bundle has one product with artificially limited supply, the only options are to relax those supply limits or cut down on companies' ability to implicitly coordinate their pricing.