10-Minute Talks

How do we understand empire in the modern age? In this 10-Minute Talk, Professor Gurminder K Bhambra challenges the idea that modern nation-states emerged as a result of the break-up of empire, and instead invites us to rethink what defines empire entirely. By considering different colonial processes and the impact these have on how we understand empires, Bhambra unpacks the specific characteristics of European empire in the modern period. 

Speaker: Professor Gurminder K Bhambra FBA, Professor of Postcolonial and Decolonial Studies, School of Global Studies, University of Sussex     

This video is for informative and educational purposes.  

For further reading, Professor Bhambra has recently published an article expanding on the themes of this talk: https://www.idunn.no/doi/10.18261/tfs.65.3.6  

Please find a blog version of this talk here: https://www.thebritishacademy.ac.uk/blog/what-are-empires-nation-states-and-colonialism/?utm_source=transistor&utm_medium=podcast&utm_id=10-minute-talk

10-Minute Talks are a series of pre-recorded talks from Fellows of the British Academy screened each Friday on YouTube and also available on Apple Podcasts. https://podcasts.apple.com/gb/podcast/10-minute-talks/id1530020476    

Subtitles, also known as closed captions, are available on our YouTube videos. You can access them by clicking on the 'CC' button or gear icon on the video. The 'CC' button and gear icon are usually located at the bottom of videos.    

Find out more about the British Academy: https://www.thebritishacademy.ac.uk/    

For future events, visit our website: https://www.thebritishacademy.ac.uk/events/    

Subscribe to our email newsletter: https://email.thebritishacademy.ac.uk/p/6P7Q-5PO/newsletter 

What is 10-Minute Talks?

The world’s leading professors explain the latest thinking in the humanities and social sciences in just 10 minutes.

My name is Gurminder Kaur Bhambra. I'm 
Professor of Historical Sociology at

the University of Sussex. Today I'm going 
to talk about the varieties of empire.

Empires and nation states are typically 
understood as two distinct types of

political organisation. There are states, 
it is claimed, that are empires and there

are others that are nation states. The key 
differences between them are as follows.

Nation states are organised around points of 
commonality across factors such as language,

culture, and tradition; whereas empires are 
seen to maintain heterogenous cultures within

their boundaries. Nation states are said to 
embody a horizontal order of rule whereby all

members are equal citizens (or in the process 
of becoming so); empires, on the other hand,

are seen as hierarchical and organised in 
relation to vertical lines of solidarity.

The elites within nation states share the 
culture of the people, whereas empires are

regarded as having a cosmopolitan elite drawn 
from the various cultures across the empire.

Finally, empires are associated with pre-modern 
societies, and will eventually, it is argued,

give way to modern nation-states that emerge as 
a consequence of the break-up of empires.

However, here there is a problem.

The period during which what are regarded as 
the archetypal nation-states of the British,

French, and Dutch were becoming consolidated 
is the very same period in which they were

establishing overseas empires. So, rather 
than nation-states coming to replace empires,

what we see is nation-states 
emerging as empires. Moreover,

these empires were significantly 
different from other types of empires.

In this talk, I address the apparent paradox 
inherent in the claim that the rise of modern

nation-states involved the displacement 
of empire at the same time as overseas

empires were being established 
by modern European nations.

The missing piece of the puzzle 
that would resolve this apparent

paradox is a proper address of colonialism.

The fact that colonial processes are not 
systematically theorised as central to

histories of the modern world is something 
that I have discussed, at length, elsewhere.

Here, I wish to highlight the 
difference made by colonialism

to the political form of European 
empire in the modern period.

The standard argument presents all types 
of empire as being essentially the same

sort of political entity, but I want 
to suggest something different. First,

there are fundamental differences between 
types of empires. Second, those states we have

understood to be nations (with empires) are more 
adequately conceptualised as colonial states.

Specifically, I distinguish two types of empire 
– ‘empires of incorporation’ and ‘empires of

extraction’ and I propose that there are three 
dominant forms of colonialism which interact

and intersect over time to create a distinct 
and modern empire based on extraction.

The three types of colonialism 
are: ‘colonialism by corporation’;

‘state practices of extraction of resources at a 
distance’; and ‘emigrationist colonialism’.

The 17th century saw the growth of commercial 
organisations – specifically, the joint stock

company – whose activities, commercial and more 
extensive, were backed by the power of their

domestic national states. Their primary objective 
was the discovery of new trades, or trading

routes, and marked a significant shift towards 
overseas commerce. Alongside trade, however,

these companies came to be involved in territorial 
acquisition and the subjugation of populations

abroad. Colonialism by corporation, then, 
relied on conquest to engage in commerce.

The latter half of the 19th century saw a turn 
away from mercantile capitalism, or commercial

colonialism, to state-managed colonialism. Various 
European states took over control of the colonies

established by state-backed companies, with 
the Dutch East Indies and the British Empire

in India being two of the most prominent examples. 
However, some of the earliest and most significant

state-backed practices of resource extraction at a 
distance included the Spanish extraction of silver

from Potosi and the Portuguese initiation of 
the trade in human beings from Africa.

The difference with the subsequent modes 
of colonisation by the English (and then

the British), the Dutch, and the French was the 
particular amalgamation of the state with the

commercial colonial entities they had supported 
in establishing new European overseas empires.

The third form of colonialism is that of 
‘emigrationist colonialism’. Despite the

popular idea that what was confronted was ‘terra 
nullius’, there is no land to which Europeans

ventured and settled that was not already 
populated and engaged in forms of husbandry that,

in liberal theory at least, was the basis of a 
right of possession. During the 19th century,

over 60 million Europeans left their 
countries of origin to make new lives

and livelihoods for themselves 
on lands inhabited by others.

These forms of colonialism have consolidated 
European global dominance politically

and economically and have brought 
into being the modern world. They

have shaped our institutions and our 
understandings of the world and have

established the difference between empires of 
incorporation and empires of extraction.

‘Empires of incorporation’, I suggest, emerge 
through the expansion and socio-economic

development of pre-existing political 
formations. They involve processes of

occupation and annexation of contiguous lands. 
This is primarily as a consequence of initiatives

by rulers within any given territory and 
involves the development of centralised

administrative and political institutions 
to govern a defined, if expanding, area.

Incorporation may give rise to resistance, but 
it was also generally inclusive in the order

of rules and obligations that organised 
the claims to territory. In contrast,

‘empires of extraction’, I argue, operate 
at a distance and are organised through

the colonial processes I set out earlier. 
They differ in three significant ways.

So first, expansion involved the subjugation 
of populations who were subject to rule by the

colonising state but were not part of its order 
of rule, which was divided between nation and

colony. The political conditions of government, 
for example, were not common across the territory

of the empire and there were different legal 
systems in the metropole and the colonies.

The second difference between the two 
types of empires is that subjugation

was organised on the assumption 
of civilisational, religious,

and/or racial superiority by the colonising 
state. The mark of ‘colonial difference’,

as Partha Chatterjee has called it, was 
central in defining who was understood

as a national citizen or subject, and part 
of the order of rule, and who was not.

Third, the land and resources of the 
colonised population – including the

populations themselves – were deemed to 
be available to the colonising state for

its own purposes and without consultation 
with them. This included the enslavement

of populations from the African continent 
who were coerced to labour in the Americas,

as well as modes of indenture and servitude 
across the Indian Ocean world.

The three key factors in distinguishing 
between empires of extraction and empires

of incorporation, then, are as follows. First, 
colonised populations being subject to rule

but not part of a common order of rule. Second, 
legitimation of colonisation on the basis of some

idea of civilisational difference and hierarchy, 
including that of scientific racism. Third,

the extraction of resources (material 
resources, taxation, and human beings

themselves) from the colonies for the primary 
advantage of those in the metropole.

These three aspects constitute empires of

extraction as fundamentally distinct 
from empires of incorporation.

There have been a multitude of empires across 
world history, but, within that history,

European overseas empires have been a distinct 
form that needs to be understood in terms of its

specific characteristics. The differences 
are not simply of form but substantive;

that is, those differences have political 
consequences that we need to reckon with.

This task is made more difficult if we 
elide all differences between empires.